2002
DOI: 10.1023/a:1013606007132
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Core Solutions in Vector-Valued Games

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
21
0

Year Published

2005
2005
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
4
3

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 35 publications
(21 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
0
21
0
Order By: Relevance
“…See also Branzei, Tijs, and Alparslan-Gök (2008) for a survey. A cooperative interval-valued game is defined by a pair (N, c I ) where N is an index set of players as before, and c I : 2 N → I(I R) is a characteristic (cost) function which assigns to every coalition S ∈ 2 N a closed interval c I (S) = [c I (S);c I (S)] (with c I (∅) = [0; 0]) where I(I R) is the set of all closed intervals in I R. It is easy to see that classical cooperative games are a special case of cooperative interval-valued games where c I (S) =c I (S) for all coalitions S ⊆ N. It should also be remarked that vector-valued games (see Fernandez, Hinojosa, and Puerto 2002) are somewhat different to interval-valued games. To define a core variant that applies to interval- The interval I is called weakly better than interval J (I J or J I), iff I ≤ J andĪ ≤J.…”
Section: A Primer On Cooperative Interval-valued Gamesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…See also Branzei, Tijs, and Alparslan-Gök (2008) for a survey. A cooperative interval-valued game is defined by a pair (N, c I ) where N is an index set of players as before, and c I : 2 N → I(I R) is a characteristic (cost) function which assigns to every coalition S ∈ 2 N a closed interval c I (S) = [c I (S);c I (S)] (with c I (∅) = [0; 0]) where I(I R) is the set of all closed intervals in I R. It is easy to see that classical cooperative games are a special case of cooperative interval-valued games where c I (S) =c I (S) for all coalitions S ⊆ N. It should also be remarked that vector-valued games (see Fernandez, Hinojosa, and Puerto 2002) are somewhat different to interval-valued games. To define a core variant that applies to interval- The interval I is called weakly better than interval J (I J or J I), iff I ≤ J andĪ ≤J.…”
Section: A Primer On Cooperative Interval-valued Gamesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the other hand, it applies to the important class of vector valued games (Fernández et al 2002a) (i.e. those games whose values are taken on R m ).…”
Section: Axiomatic Approach To the Extended Shapley Valuementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our analysis is completely different instead of imposing conditions on the argument of the characteristic function we extend the nature of the payoffs. Particular instances of this model have been already considered in (Fernández et al 2002a;Granot 1977;Nishizaki and Sakawa 2001;Suijs 2000;Suijs et al 1998Suijs et al , 1999Timmer 2001).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…An extensive analysis for the class of vector-valued transferable utility (TU) games is found in Hinojosa [6], and Fernández, Hinojosa and Puerto [4] where the classical individual and collective rationality principles are extended using two dif-ferent orderings in the payoff space. The first ordering reflects a very compromising attitude in negotiation with coalitions admitting payoffs that are not worse in all the components than any payoffs that they can ensure by themselves.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%