2016
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2860002
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Dividing Goods and Bads Under Additive Utilities

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

0
21
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
3
2
1

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 14 publications
(21 citation statements)
references
References 2 publications
0
21
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Regarding fair division (see, e.g., Brams & Taylor, 1996;Bouveret, Chevaleyre, & Maudet, 2016;, while there is some work on chore division (see, e.g., Aziz, Rauchecker, Schryen, & Walsh, 2017;Bogomolnaia, Moulin, Sandomirskiy, & Yanovskaya, 2016, for recent work), not much is known about settings where an item can be seen as negative for an agent and positive for another one while a third agent does not care about receiving it; 6 still, there are many pratical contexts where this assumption is plausible, such as the allocation of papers to reviewers. If there is no constraint on the allocation, then obviously an item will be assigned to an agent who likes it, provided there is at least one such agent; but if there are constraints (such as balancedness), then it may be the case that an agent gets an item she does not want even though someone expressed a positive preference for it.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Regarding fair division (see, e.g., Brams & Taylor, 1996;Bouveret, Chevaleyre, & Maudet, 2016;, while there is some work on chore division (see, e.g., Aziz, Rauchecker, Schryen, & Walsh, 2017;Bogomolnaia, Moulin, Sandomirskiy, & Yanovskaya, 2016, for recent work), not much is known about settings where an item can be seen as negative for an agent and positive for another one while a third agent does not care about receiving it; 6 still, there are many pratical contexts where this assumption is plausible, such as the allocation of papers to reviewers. If there is no constraint on the allocation, then obviously an item will be assigned to an agent who likes it, provided there is at least one such agent; but if there are constraints (such as balancedness), then it may be the case that an agent gets an item she does not want even though someone expressed a positive preference for it.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Let z be a competitive allocation Pareto inferior to the feasible allocation y. Some agent i * strictly prefers y i * to z i * which implies p • z i * < p • y i * by (1). So if we show p • z i ≤ p • y i for all i, we contradict z N = y N by summing up these inequalities.…”
Section: Proofmentioning
confidence: 94%
“…Here CR splits a between agents 1 and 2, which coalition {1, 3} blocks by giving 2 3 of a to agent 1. Remark 2: It is easy to check that CR meets Independence of Lost Bids, the translation of Maskin Monotonicity under linear preferences: see the precise definition in [1]. Just as in Proposition 2 of that paper, CR is characterized by, essentially, combining this property with Efficiency.…”
Section: Proofmentioning
confidence: 95%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The problem of effective resource allocation occurs in various applied problems [4]. If the resource value is limited and the participants interests do not coincide, a conflict situation arises.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%