2007
DOI: 10.1007/s11079-007-9008-x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Estimated Open Economy New Keynesian Phillips Curves for the G7

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

5
50
2

Year Published

2007
2007
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 53 publications
(57 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
5
50
2
Order By: Relevance
“…However, the elasticity of demand of the firm's product, ε, cannot be estimated econometrically, as it does not appear in the estimation equation, but has to be calibrated in order to derive an empirical value for the the elasticity of substitution between capital and the variable factors of production, φ. In calibrating ε we follow the literature (see Gali et al [7], Leith and Malley [11]) and adopt a value of 11 as a baseline implying a steady-state markup of prices over marginal costs µ = In the model the price set by a firm is its output price. The output is then used for final consumption demand and intermediate inputs of other forms at home or abroad.…”
Section: Empirical Specificationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, the elasticity of demand of the firm's product, ε, cannot be estimated econometrically, as it does not appear in the estimation equation, but has to be calibrated in order to derive an empirical value for the the elasticity of substitution between capital and the variable factors of production, φ. In calibrating ε we follow the literature (see Gali et al [7], Leith and Malley [11]) and adopt a value of 11 as a baseline implying a steady-state markup of prices over marginal costs µ = In the model the price set by a firm is its output price. The output is then used for final consumption demand and intermediate inputs of other forms at home or abroad.…”
Section: Empirical Specificationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Our analysis is partly related to Leith and Malley (2007) and Rumler (2007), who also estimate open-economy versions of the NKPC although in a less explicit way. In contrast to our paper, these authors focus on parameters such as the degree of backwardand forward-lookingness, the Calvo probability of a price change, and the degree of imperfect substitutability between domestic and foreign intermediate inputs, without examining in more detail the role of external-sector inflation drivers.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The primary evidence stems from cross country comparisons. Examples are Banerjee and Batini (2004), Benigno and López-Salido (2006), Leith and Malley (2007) or Rumler (2007). This evidence is in most cases based upon GMM estimation with additional aspects of an open economy.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This evidence is in most cases based upon GMM estimation with additional aspects of an open economy. While the open economy aspect seems to be unimportant for German Phillips curve (at least according to Banerjee and Batini, 2004;Leith and Malley, 2007), their results vary considerably with respect to the degree of nominal price rigidity. The estimated average frequency of price re-optimization ranges from 2.5 quarters (Banerjee and Batini, 2004) to 13 quarters (Leith and Malley, 2007).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation