2013
DOI: 10.1016/j.envsoft.2013.02.001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Expanding risk consideration in integrated models – The role of downside risk aversion in irrigation decisions

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
22
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 27 publications
(24 citation statements)
references
References 28 publications
2
22
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We thus assume that cultivation decisions are made based on good agricultural practice with no incentives to produce at lower cost, as there is no protection against low-yield outcomes. 19 In Heimfarth et al (2012), different regression approaches have been considered, that is, linear and quadratic trend models, as well as OLS and robust regression approaches (Finger 2010). ) values in the strike-level section reflect cases of poor quantile regression results with respect to the estimates of intercept and slope coefficient.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…We thus assume that cultivation decisions are made based on good agricultural practice with no incentives to produce at lower cost, as there is no protection against low-yield outcomes. 19 In Heimfarth et al (2012), different regression approaches have been considered, that is, linear and quadratic trend models, as well as OLS and robust regression approaches (Finger 2010). ) values in the strike-level section reflect cases of poor quantile regression results with respect to the estimates of intercept and slope coefficient.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…11 Compared to weather station data, the gridded 7 See Di Falco and Chavas (2006) and Finger (2013 for a motivation of this functional form. 8 As the power utility function implies decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA) preferences, we tested sensitivity toward changes in the initial wealth parameter and found no qualitative differences in our results.…”
Section: Data a Weather Datamentioning
confidence: 99%
“…To investigate the role of risk aversion on optimal nitrogen use decision, we follow Finger (2013) and investigate optimal input use for 4 different scenarios. With being either 0, 1, 2 or 3 taken to represent a gradient from zero to moderate (downside) risk aversion these are: r2 = 0, 1 , 2 and 3 and r3 = 0, − …”
Section: The Economic Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Calanca 2007), consideration of downside risks is even more important in the context of climate change impact assessments. So far, however, the problem of integrating downside risk aversion in bio-economic models has been tackled only in a few studies Finger 2013;Finger 2013, Finger andCalanca, 2011). The goal of our study was to integrate downside risks in a bio-economic model and examine the implications of risk aversion for optimal nitrogen use in grassland production under current and future climatic conditions.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Finger (2013) recently applied the Antle (1987) model to estimate the optimal N fertilizer rate and irrigation rate for corn production while considering both the variance and skewness of net returns and found that downside risk reduced the optimal N fertilizer rate and increased the optimal irrigation rate. Applying this approach to determine optimal N rates for continuous corn, corn grown after cotton, and corn grown after soybean would be a unique application of the Antle (1987) model that augments traditional risk analyses with useful information about downside risk.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%