2007
DOI: 10.1257/aer.97.5.1731
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Fatal Attraction: Salience, Naïveté, and Sophistication in Experimental “Hide-and-Seek” Games

Abstract: " Hide-and-seek" games are zero-sum two-person Game theorists have been intrigued by hideand-seek games-zero-sum two-person games in which one player wins by matching the other's decision and the other wins by mismatching-for more than 50 years (John von Neumann 1953). These games cleanly model a strategic problem that is central to many economic, political, and social settings, as well as the obvious military and security applications. Examples include entry games where entry requires a differentiated produ… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

8
151
1
4

Year Published

2009
2009
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
6
2
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 188 publications
(164 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
8
151
1
4
Order By: Relevance
“…In particular, the provision of information signi…cantly raises the participation of voters supporting the slightly larger team relative to the participation of voters supporting the smaller team, thus a¤ecting the election's results. 7 The correlation between closeness and turnout observed in the laboratory is consistent with results in the related empirical literature [see, for example, Shachar and Nalebu¤ (1999)]. Feddersen and Sandroni (2006) show that this correlation can be explained using a model where voters have ethical preferences.…”
Section: The E¤ect Of Information On Subjects'turnout Decisionssupporting
confidence: 84%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In particular, the provision of information signi…cantly raises the participation of voters supporting the slightly larger team relative to the participation of voters supporting the smaller team, thus a¤ecting the election's results. 7 The correlation between closeness and turnout observed in the laboratory is consistent with results in the related empirical literature [see, for example, Shachar and Nalebu¤ (1999)]. Feddersen and Sandroni (2006) show that this correlation can be explained using a model where voters have ethical preferences.…”
Section: The E¤ect Of Information On Subjects'turnout Decisionssupporting
confidence: 84%
“…For closely divided preferences, on the contrary, we observe important quantitative di¤erences between the subjects'turnout and the predictions of the theoretical model underlying the experiment. 7 Although Figure 1 reveals a clear and signi…cant e¤ect of closeness on participation, the …gure masks important and unexpected di¤erences between teams for a given distribution of preferences. The heterogeneous e¤ect of closeness between teams is presented in Figure 2, which decomposes turnout as a function of the size of the teams.…”
Section: The E¤ect Of Information On Subjects'turnout Decisionsmentioning
confidence: 95%
“…This difference in beliefs results in equilibrium strategies (and induced mixed 4 While the assumptions of the F i above preclude this case, it can be approximated arbitrarily closely by F i that do satisfy the assumptions. 5 Recall that strategies are maps from type to choice probabilities.…”
Section: Subjective Hqrementioning
confidence: 99%
“…This counts against H3. 5 We test H4 by first estimating what weights, when attached to each rule for each category, can best explain the choice of labels in Experiment I under the assumption that each rule yields the distribution of choices revealed by Experiment II (see Crawford and Iriberri 2007, for a similar approach). Using maximum likelihood, we estimate these for each category individually as well as in the aggregate by pooling all the decision problems.…”
Section: Results: Experiments IImentioning
confidence: 99%