2018
DOI: 10.3386/w24830
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Financial Incentives and Earnings of Disability Insurance Recipients: Evidence from a Notch Design

Abstract: Most countries reduce Disability Insurance (DI) benefits for beneficiaries earning above a specified threshold. Such an earnings threshold generates a discontinuous increase in tax liability -a notch-and creates an incentive to keep earnings below the threshold. Exploiting such a notch in Austria, we provide transparent and credible identification of the effect of financial incentives on DI beneficiaries' earnings. Using rich administrative data, we document large and sharp bunching at the earnings threshold. … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
21
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 14 publications
(22 citation statements)
references
References 23 publications
1
21
0
Order By: Relevance
“…find that replacing a notch at the exemption threshold with a kink in the Norwegian DI program was likely to reduce program costs. In contrast, Ruh & Staubli (2019) exploit a notch in the Austrian DI program, and conclude that abolishing the notch would increase program costs. 8 They find that most of the increased government revenue comes from extensive margin responses if the benefit schedule is relaxed.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 95%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…find that replacing a notch at the exemption threshold with a kink in the Norwegian DI program was likely to reduce program costs. In contrast, Ruh & Staubli (2019) exploit a notch in the Austrian DI program, and conclude that abolishing the notch would increase program costs. 8 They find that most of the increased government revenue comes from extensive margin responses if the benefit schedule is relaxed.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 95%
“…If one does not account for this response, the response of the marginal bunching individual will be overstated and the estimated elasticity upward biased. In order to adjust for extensive margin responses, I follow Ruh & Staubli (2019) and assume that the distribution of recipients who stop working is the same as the observed earnings distribution above the kink. 33 In Section 6, I show that the estimated elasticity is very close to the theoretical elasticity when incorporating this adjustment procedure in a simulation exercise.…”
Section: Threats To Identificationmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…For example, beneficiaries continue to receive all SSDI benefits after initially returning to work, but may eventually lose their cash benefits completely after engaging in substantial work activity (with earnings above a threshold level set by SSA) for a sustained amount of time-a phenomenon commonly called the "cash cliff". This complete loss of benefits may inhibit some beneficiaries from engaging in substantial work (Ruh & Staubli, 2019;Schimmel, Stapleton, & Song, 2011;Stapleton, O'Day, Livermore, & Imparato, 2006). Qualitative evidence suggests that both the fear of losing benefits and confusion related to the complexity of SSDI rules can inhibit work (O'Day, Martin, Burak, Freeman, Feeney, Lim, Kelley, & Morrison, 2016).…”
Section: Overview Of Podmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, Hoynes and Moffitt (1999); Benitez-Silva et al (2011); Weathers II and Hemmeter (2011);and Bütler et al (2015) find no effects of financial incentives to work in the US and Switzerland. However, Campolieti and Riddell (2012); Kostol and Mogstad (2014); and Ruh and Staubli (2016) find positive responses in Canada, Norway and Austria. Zaresani (2017) suggests that the relative size of the incentives to work induced by a program versus the adjustment costs that individuals face when changing their labor supply could possibly explain these disparate findings.…”
mentioning
confidence: 91%