2020
DOI: 10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2020.103519
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Fiscal equalization and the tax structure

Abstract: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz ge… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
6
1
1

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 15 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 57 publications
0
6
1
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Existing literature furthermore suggests that property tax and consumption tax may both be distortionary, although it is unclear on which one is relatively more distortionary (Arnold, 2008b;Cashin, 1995;Helms, 1985;Holm-Hadulla, 2020;Mendoza et al, 1997;Romero-Ávila & Strauch, 2008). We find no clear significant differences between the two, although property tax is found to be more distortionary in the shorter-run (after three years instead of five years).…”
Section: Revenuescontrasting
confidence: 47%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Existing literature furthermore suggests that property tax and consumption tax may both be distortionary, although it is unclear on which one is relatively more distortionary (Arnold, 2008b;Cashin, 1995;Helms, 1985;Holm-Hadulla, 2020;Mendoza et al, 1997;Romero-Ávila & Strauch, 2008). We find no clear significant differences between the two, although property tax is found to be more distortionary in the shorter-run (after three years instead of five years).…”
Section: Revenuescontrasting
confidence: 47%
“…Taxes are generally expected to distort growth (Cashin, 1995;Romero-Ávila & Strauch, 2008). However, there is some discussion on the relative distortionary extent; Some claim property tax to be relatively distortionary (Barro, 1990;Helms, 1985;, while others argue that it actually is relatively non-distortionary (Arnold, 2008a;Holm-Hadulla, 2020). Similarly, sales and gross receipts tax is both found to be relatively distortionary (Mendoza, Milesi-Ferretti, & Asea, 1997) and non-distortionary (Arnold, 2008a;Barro, 1990;.…”
Section: Public Finance and Economic Growthmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One of them comes from the tax industry. Most countries in the world impose taxes on their citizens, but some taxes are used as the main source of income for the country except for countries rich in natural resources that do not collect taxes (Holm-Hadulla, 2020;Yang & Zhou, 2021). Tax provisions in each country vary but generally follow the same tax principles or rules.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The source of tax collection income from various sources comes from local taxes (Darwin, 2010;Holm-Hadulla, 2020;Zhai et al, 2021). Regional Tax is a mandatory contribution to the region that is owned by a person or entity that is coercive based on the applicable laws and regulations and is used to finance the administration of regional government and regional development for the prosperity of the people (Mardiasmo, 2006(Mardiasmo, , 2016(Mardiasmo, , 2018.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%