2019
DOI: 10.3982/ecta14930
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

How Destructive Is Innovation?

Abstract: Entrants and incumbents can create new products and displace the products of competitors. Incumbents can also improve their existing products. How much of aggregate productivity growth occurs through each of these channels? Using data from the U.S. Longitudinal Business Database on all nonfarm private businesses from 1983 to 2013, we arrive at three main conclusions: First, most growth appears to come from incumbents. We infer this from the modest employment share of entering firms (defined as those less than … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

7
80
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 152 publications
(87 citation statements)
references
References 51 publications
7
80
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This theoretical attribute is also available in Howitt (1999) in that the economic growth rate is eventually supported by the growth from creative destruction (vertical innovation) rather than variety expansion (horizontal innovation) in the steady-state equilibrium. In addition, this implication is consistent with the empirical finding in Garcia-Macia et al (2016), who decompose the aggregate total factor productivity growth for the US within the periods 1976-1986 and 2003-2013 and find that the contribution of growth from creative destruction is overwhelmingly larger than that from new varieties.…”
Section: Population-growth Conditionsupporting
confidence: 88%
“…This theoretical attribute is also available in Howitt (1999) in that the economic growth rate is eventually supported by the growth from creative destruction (vertical innovation) rather than variety expansion (horizontal innovation) in the steady-state equilibrium. In addition, this implication is consistent with the empirical finding in Garcia-Macia et al (2016), who decompose the aggregate total factor productivity growth for the US within the periods 1976-1986 and 2003-2013 and find that the contribution of growth from creative destruction is overwhelmingly larger than that from new varieties.…”
Section: Population-growth Conditionsupporting
confidence: 88%
“…They find that incumbents account for the bulk of productivity growth in the economy. Although their results are consistent with the results of FHK for the manufacturing sector, we should be cautious in comparing the two results, since Garcia-Macia et al (2016) do not use the FHK decomposition but rather use a decomposition derived from their model. We set g , which determines the efficiency growth rate of continuing firms, to match the contribution of entry and exit to U.S. aggregate manufacturing productivity growth, which FHK find to be 25 percent.…”
Section: Calibrationsupporting
confidence: 59%
“…We are not aware of any work that calculates the FHK productivity decomposition for the entire U.S. economy. The paper by Garcia-Macia et al (2016), however, is one of the few papers that use data for the entire U.S. economy to study the relative importance of incumbents and entrants in accounting for productivity growth. They find that incumbents account for the bulk of productivity growth in the economy.…”
Section: Calibrationmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Moreover, recent empirical studies (e.g., Bartelsman & Doms, ; Garcia‐Macia, Hsieh, & Klenow, ) find that existing firms’ own‐product improvement is a major source of economic growth, rather than creative destruction by market entrants. In particular, Garcia‐Macia et al () report that 80.2% of total‐factor productivity (TFP) growth for 2003–2013 in the United States is attributed to innovation by existing firms. For simplicity, in our model, we assume that R&D is performed only by existing firms that are producing goods for the market.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%