2014
DOI: 10.1016/j.red.2013.04.002
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Is smoking a fiscal good?

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

5
2

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 8 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 38 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This is because the shape of the age-dependent component of labor productivity (s) is the single-most important determinant of the shape of the hours profile generated from the model, and the productivity profile estimated from Hansen (1993) peaks relatively early. While it is standard practice in the literature to treat the age-dependent component (s) as observable, there are studies that treat this as an unobservable structural parameter, and calibrate it to match the shape of the hours profile in the data (Bullard and Feigenbaum, 2007;Bagchi and Feigenbaum, 2014). As one would expect, the calibrated productivity profiles in these studies peak significantly later in life (about age 52 or even later), relative to the productivity profile estimated from Hansen (1993), which peaks at age 42.…”
Section: Baseline Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This is because the shape of the age-dependent component of labor productivity (s) is the single-most important determinant of the shape of the hours profile generated from the model, and the productivity profile estimated from Hansen (1993) peaks relatively early. While it is standard practice in the literature to treat the age-dependent component (s) as observable, there are studies that treat this as an unobservable structural parameter, and calibrate it to match the shape of the hours profile in the data (Bullard and Feigenbaum, 2007;Bagchi and Feigenbaum, 2014). As one would expect, the calibrated productivity profiles in these studies peak significantly later in life (about age 52 or even later), relative to the productivity profile estimated from Hansen (1993), which peaks at age 42.…”
Section: Baseline Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One potential strategy to improve the model's fit along this dimension is to treat the age‐dependent component of labor productivity ϵt ${\epsilon }_{t}$ as an unobservable structural parameter. Treating ϵt ${\epsilon }_{t}$ as an unobservable parameter would eliminate any selection bias arising from measuring it as residual wages (Bagchi & Feigenbaum, 2014; Bullard & Feigenbaum, 2007).…”
Section: Baseline Steady‐state Equilibriummentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, I treat the age-dependent component of labor productivity (s) as observable, whereas in reality it is an unobservable structural parameter. Treating (s) as an unobservable parameter could potentially eliminate any selection bias arising from measuring it as residual wages (Bullard and Feigenbaum 2007;Bagchi and Feigenbaum 2014). Second, households in the current model smooth consumption across the work life and retirement (the life-cycle motive), and also across the stochastic realizations of the idiosyncratic productivity shock (the precautionary motive).…”
Section: Baseline Economymentioning
confidence: 99%