1990
DOI: 10.1007/bf01753707
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Monotonicity of the core and value in dynamic cooperative games

Abstract: Abstract:We examine behavior of the core and value of certain classes of cooperative games in which a dynamic aspect is introduced. New players are added to the games while the underlying structure is held constant. This is done by considering games that satisfy properties like convexity, or games that are derived from optimization problems in which a player's addition can be defined naturally. For such games we give conditions regarding monotonicity of the core and value.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
7
0

Year Published

1998
1998
2018
2018

Publication Types

Select...
6
2
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 24 publications
(7 citation statements)
references
References 25 publications
0
7
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Intuitively, cross-monotonicity requires that the price charged to any individual in a group does not increase as the group expands. There is a large body of literature [Dutta 1990;Dutta and Ray 1989;Hokari 2000;Jain and Vazirani 2002;Moulin 1999;Rosenthal 1990;Shapley 1953;Sprumont 1990] on cross-monotonic cost-sharing schemes for submodular cost functions, 1 a subclass of cost functions of particular interest. Many mechanisms exist, prominent among them the Shapley value [Shapley 1953], which minimizes the worst-case efficiency loss, and the Dutta-Ray solution [Dutta and Ray 1989].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Intuitively, cross-monotonicity requires that the price charged to any individual in a group does not increase as the group expands. There is a large body of literature [Dutta 1990;Dutta and Ray 1989;Hokari 2000;Jain and Vazirani 2002;Moulin 1999;Rosenthal 1990;Shapley 1953;Sprumont 1990] on cross-monotonic cost-sharing schemes for submodular cost functions, 1 a subclass of cost functions of particular interest. Many mechanisms exist, prominent among them the Shapley value [Shapley 1953], which minimizes the worst-case efficiency loss, and the Dutta-Ray solution [Dutta and Ray 1989].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Proof: Rosenthal (1990) shows that the Shapley value on convex games satisfies populationmonotonicity. In other words, addition of new players expands opportunities of all players, and all players in the new game are better off.…”
Section: Shapley Value Allocationsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It does not hold on the class of either convex or concave games since the Shapley value 4 (Shapley 1953) satisfies all the axioms on these domains (Sprumont 1990;Rosenthal 1990 (1, 3) = 12, and v (1, 2, 3) = 20. It is easy to check that v and v are super-additive games, ϕ Sh (v) = (6, 4), and ϕ Sh (v ) = (5.5, 6, 8.5).…”
Section: Proof Of Claim 3 Suppose By Way Of Contradiction That For Allmentioning
confidence: 99%