“…Baker, Gibbons and Murphy (2002, p. 39) define relational contracts as ‘information agreements sustained by the value of future relationships,’ and Gibbons and Henderson (2012a, p. 1350) initially define them as ‘collaboration sustained by the shadow of the future as opposed to formal contracts enforced by courts’ and subsequently observe that the parties to such a contract seek to maximise their roles in and rewards from cooperating—that is, they see value in working together (2012b, p. 681). Relational contracts ‘facilitate collaboration and repeated interactions’ between parties (de Figueiredo & Silverman, 2017, p. 234) and can support achievement of outcomes that may otherwise not be possible (Bernstein, 2015). In short, relational contracts are ‘incomplete agreements’ with agreed common goals but without detailed plans (Macneil, 1978; Milgrom & Roberts, 1992), ‘informal and self‐enforced’ (Halac, 2012, p. 750) and ‘proactive and flexible’ (Cheung, 2001, p. 39), assuming that both parties inherently maximise their benefits by building a trusted and cooperative relationship (Jeffries & Reed, 2000; Williamson, 1991).…”