1978
DOI: 10.2307/1883177
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Optimal Redistributive Taxation When Individual Welfare Depends Upon Relative Income

Abstract: JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.. Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

6
176
0
3

Year Published

1981
1981
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 352 publications
(185 citation statements)
references
References 6 publications
6
176
0
3
Order By: Relevance
“…For instance, see Cole et al (1992); Corneo and Jeanne (1997);. Boskin and Sheshinski (1978) and Oswald (1983) theoretically analyze tax policy implications of relative utility, while Abel (1990); Bakshi and Chen (1996); Gali (1994);and Campbell and Cochrane (1999) examined such relative effects on asset pricing. Frank (1985) and Frank (2005) show that relative concerns are more important for positional goods consumption than other goods such as leisure, and that the structure of utility functions with relative concerns over different types of goods is of key importance in the valuations of social welfare.…”
Section: Data Descriptionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, see Cole et al (1992); Corneo and Jeanne (1997);. Boskin and Sheshinski (1978) and Oswald (1983) theoretically analyze tax policy implications of relative utility, while Abel (1990); Bakshi and Chen (1996); Gali (1994);and Campbell and Cochrane (1999) examined such relative effects on asset pricing. Frank (1985) and Frank (2005) show that relative concerns are more important for positional goods consumption than other goods such as leisure, and that the structure of utility functions with relative concerns over different types of goods is of key importance in the valuations of social welfare.…”
Section: Data Descriptionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…k Example 3 clari®es that negative interdependence is something distinct from asserting that one's well-being is strictly decreasing in others' incomes. In other words, spite does not entail negative interdependence; our formalization of interdependent preferences is thus di¨erent from the usual formulation (such as in Boskin and Sheshinski 1978, Oswald 1983, Villar 1988and Galõ Â 1994. We note, however, that the concepts of negative interdependence and spite may turn out to be equivalent depending on the further restrictions one may wish to impose on the preference relation x.…”
Section: Examplesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Clearly, this preference relation would be represented on n by the utility function u aY y log a log a m aY y , and is thus a weighted average of independent and strongly relative preference relations (cf. Boskin andSheshinski, 1978, andTuomala, 1990). As gets smaller, the``independence'' of this particular preference relation increases, and as gets larger, the``relative income e¨ect'' becomes more pressing.…”
Section: Quasi-relative Preferencesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…For example, in structuring optimal taxation, a desire for status calls for higher marginal taxes (Boskin and Sheshinski, 1978;Oswald, 1983;Blomquist, 1993;Aronsson and JohanssonStenman, 2008;Wendner and Goulder, 2008). Concerns about status and relative deprivation bear on labor supply (Neumark and Postlewaite, 1998), economic growth (Easterlin, 1974;Clark et al, 2008), poverty measurement (Sen, 1973), migration decisions (Stark and Taylor, 1991), and risk-taking behavior (Callan et al, 2008;Haisley et al, 2008).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%