2014
DOI: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.07.013
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Preemptive bidding, target resistance, and takeover premiums

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
15
1
1

Year Published

2014
2014
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 83 publications
(17 citation statements)
references
References 60 publications
0
15
1
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Otherwise, if the entry of potential competitors is not preempted, high control benefits increase the takeover premium as in the target resistance theory (Bebchuk (1994)). Our results differ from Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2011), who also investigate the impact of preemptive bidding relative to that of target resistance, as we find that potential competition is the key driver of takeover premia whereas target resistance plays a role only for relatively weak bidders.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Otherwise, if the entry of potential competitors is not preempted, high control benefits increase the takeover premium as in the target resistance theory (Bebchuk (1994)). Our results differ from Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2011), who also investigate the impact of preemptive bidding relative to that of target resistance, as we find that potential competition is the key driver of takeover premia whereas target resistance plays a role only for relatively weak bidders.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 99%
“…This reservation price is learned by the winning bidder only at the end of the bidding process and, at that point, if the winning bid is below the minimum bid the bidder has the possibility to raise the offer. In their empirical test, Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2011) provide evidence that the high premia observed in single bidder contests result from the need to overcome target resistance rather than potential competition. Our model differs from Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2011) in that we endogenize this minimum acceptable offer, which, in each stage of the negotiation, equals the value of the target shareholders' best credible threat.…”
Section: Takeover Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…These discussions suggest a negative relationship between policy uncertainty and the bid premiums. We run the bid premiums regressions on PU while controlling for other firm and deal characteristics, including SIZE, MARKET-TO-BOOK RATIO, BOOK LEVERAGE, PAST 12 MONTH STOCK RETURNS, FIRM AGE, AVERAGE SALES GROWTH, NONCASH WORKING CAPITAL, EXCESS CASH, STOCK DUMMY, CASH DUMMY (the mixed stock-cash payment is left out to avoid perfect collinearity), HIGH TECH DUMMY, DIVERSIFYING DUMMY, HOSTILE DUMMY, PUBLIC TARGET DUMMY, and CHALLENGE DUMMY (Officer (2003), Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2014)). Columns 1 and 2 of Table 6 report the results of the bid-premium regressions with and without industry fixed effects, respectively.…”
Section: B Policy Uncertainty Payment Considerations and Bid Premiumsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Like Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2014), we consider only the premium corresponding to the final offer. This is the winning bid in a successfully completed takeover or otherwise the last withdrawn bid in an unsuccessful takeover.…”
Section: Target Valuation: Offer Premiummentioning
confidence: 99%