2016
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2757967
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Procedures for Eliciting Time Preferences

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
4
0

Year Published

2021
2021
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
2
2
1

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 5 publications
(4 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
0
4
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Respondents were asked to click on the radio button that indicated which option they would choose and how confident they felt that this was the better option for them This method is most like the way in which values are usually elicited, although it tries to emphasise equivalence and makes the analogous choice implications explicit, whereas some direct formats couch the exercise in terms of the maximum amount respondents would be willing to pay to acquire an option or else in terms of the minimum amount they would be prepared to accept in exchange for selling the option. For example, Freeman et al (2016) used two types of direct valuation procedure (one linked to the Becker et al (1964) incentive mechanism, the other involving a second-price auction) which asked respondents to state the lowest sum they would prefer to receive tomorrow instead of receiving €20 at a later date. Likewise, TSK asked participants to state, hypothetically, "the smallest immediate cash payment for which they would be willing to exchange the delayed payment" (p.231).…”
Section: Direct Valuation (Dv)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Respondents were asked to click on the radio button that indicated which option they would choose and how confident they felt that this was the better option for them This method is most like the way in which values are usually elicited, although it tries to emphasise equivalence and makes the analogous choice implications explicit, whereas some direct formats couch the exercise in terms of the maximum amount respondents would be willing to pay to acquire an option or else in terms of the minimum amount they would be prepared to accept in exchange for selling the option. For example, Freeman et al (2016) used two types of direct valuation procedure (one linked to the Becker et al (1964) incentive mechanism, the other involving a second-price auction) which asked respondents to state the lowest sum they would prefer to receive tomorrow instead of receiving €20 at a later date. Likewise, TSK asked participants to state, hypothetically, "the smallest immediate cash payment for which they would be willing to exchange the delayed payment" (p.231).…”
Section: Direct Valuation (Dv)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In order to estimate consistent time preferences, intertemporal choices must follow the monetary monotonicity property, which requires that subjects prefer more money to less given a fixed time horizon (Freeman et al, 2016). We, therefore, excluded inconsistent responses, where participants were willing to wait for a certain amount, but not willing to wait for a higher gain.…”
Section: Conceptual Framework: Outcomes Of Interest and Hypothesesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, most of the evidence demonstrates that the choosing and matching methods yield inconsistent discount rates (Hardisty, Thompson, et al, 2013;Cohen et al, 2020). Specifically, a lower discount rate is found via matching methods than via choosing methods (Read & Roelofsma, 2003;Freeman et al, 2016). Furthermore, discount rates from monetary gains are higher than those from losses (Thaler, 1981), known as "gain-loss asymmetry" or the "sign effect."…”
Section: Tasks and Discount Ratesmentioning
confidence: 99%