2018
DOI: 10.1016/j.amc.2017.08.049
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Promoting cooperation by punishing minority

Abstract: Punishment is an effective way to sustain cooperation among selfish individuals. In most of previous studies, objects of punishment are set to be defectors. In this paper, we propose a mechanism of punishment, in which individuals with the majority strategy will punish those with the minority strategy in a public goods game group. Both theoretical analysis and simulation show that the cooperation level can be greatly enhanced by punishing minority. For no punishment or small values of punishment fine, the frac… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
5

Citation Types

0
23
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
9
1

Relationship

3
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 78 publications
(23 citation statements)
references
References 54 publications
0
23
0
Order By: Relevance
“…However, self-regarding individuals constantly strive to maximize their own personal benefit which would inevitably lead to the collapse of cooperation, in the scenario where what is best for the collectivity is at odds with what is best for an individual. This is referred to as social dilemma of cooperation [4,5,6,7], which has received considerable attention in recent years [8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26,27,28]. To overcome this conflict social institutions frequently apply two control mechanisms, that is, rewards (positive incentives) for cooperation [29,30,31,32,33,34,35,36,37,38] and punishments (negative incentives) for defection [39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49]…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, self-regarding individuals constantly strive to maximize their own personal benefit which would inevitably lead to the collapse of cooperation, in the scenario where what is best for the collectivity is at odds with what is best for an individual. This is referred to as social dilemma of cooperation [4,5,6,7], which has received considerable attention in recent years [8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26,27,28]. To overcome this conflict social institutions frequently apply two control mechanisms, that is, rewards (positive incentives) for cooperation [29,30,31,32,33,34,35,36,37,38] and punishments (negative incentives) for defection [39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49]…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…13,19,36,46,50,58 One prominently discussed solution is the employment of pro-social punishment, that is, punishing uncooperative individuals by lowering their income. 11,14,32,33,44,51,54,59,61,69 In particular, two different ways of punishment are studied, namely, peer punishment and pool punishment. The former refers to that group individuals can impose fines on the violators directly and its additional cost.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Similarly, it represents a social dilemma. To investigate this issue, several novel approaches, besides studies addressing known rules [8], have been proposed to explain the appearance and survival of cooperation above so-called social dilemma, such as diversity [9][10][11][12], social influence [13][14][15], reputation [16][17][18][19], conformity [20],co-evolution [21][22][23][24], punishment [25,26], reward [27,28], rubust [29], spatial structure [30], to name but a few. Accordingly, spatial structure, referred to as network reciprocity, is known to have an impact on the evolution of cooperation [31][32][33][34].…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%