2014
DOI: 10.1057/iga.2013.16
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Revolving door lobbyists and interest representation

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
57
0
5

Year Published

2015
2015
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
4
3

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 95 publications
(65 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
3
57
0
5
Order By: Relevance
“…Finally, it may well be worth focusing on the assumption of consumer sovereignty since agency problems constitute an intrusion of producer interests into exchange relationships. Thus, we might ask whether there is a meaningful market in lobby services, a question recently raised by LaPira and Thomas (2014). Is the lobby market sufficiently developed so that producers offer a differentiated array of services?…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Finally, it may well be worth focusing on the assumption of consumer sovereignty since agency problems constitute an intrusion of producer interests into exchange relationships. Thus, we might ask whether there is a meaningful market in lobby services, a question recently raised by LaPira and Thomas (2014). Is the lobby market sufficiently developed so that producers offer a differentiated array of services?…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…372-373) allow for some minor slippage between the interests of clients and contract lobbyists, they assume that the behavior of in-house lobbyists is fully controlled via hierarchical monitoring (Kersh, 2000, p. 241). Indeed, with few exceptions (Leech, 2013;LaPira and Thomas, 2014), lobbyists per se have now largely vanished as interesting actors in studies of interest representation. 1 They are at least implicitly viewed as superconducting transmitters linking the issues of concern to interest organizations to officials with no loss of energy and perfect fidelity.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…LaPira and Thomas (2014) estimate the size of the revolving door lobbyist community, and both Baumgartner et al (2009) and Lazarus and McKay (2012) begin to assess how influential these lobbyists are. But we still have had little idea of who is most likely to become a revolving door lobbyist.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In response to the recent acceleration of Congress members and congressional staff becoming lobbyists, however, focus on the topic has increased (e.g., Vidal et al 2012, LaPira and Thomas 2014, Baumgartner et al 2009. This article adds to the growing body of research by asking which former members of Congress are most likely to become lobbyists.…”
Section: Leech 2013)mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation