2013
DOI: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2013.06.014
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Shared rewarding overcomes defection traps in generalized volunteer's dilemmas

Abstract: For societies to produce or safeguard public goods, costly voluntary contributions are often required. From the perspective of each individual, however, it is advantageous not to volunteer such contributions, in the hope that other individuals will carry the associated costs. This conflict can be modeled as a volunteer's dilemma. To encourage rational individuals to make voluntary contributions, a government or other social organizations can offer rewards, to be shared among the volunteers. Here we apply such … Show more

Help me understand this report
View preprint versions

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
34
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 37 publications
(34 citation statements)
references
References 46 publications
0
34
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Consequently, attempts to artificially produce prosocial norm spillovers in a purely lab‐based setting (e.g., Peysakhovich & Rand, ) cannot tell us much about the extent to which cultural and societal norms are internalized by individuals in the real world (Galizzi & Navarro‐Martínez, ). Finally, our results suggest that many social and cultural incentives that sustain volunteering (Chen et al, ), such as favorable public recognition and associated feelings of pride, are not fully internalized, and are therefore “fragile” in the sense that they require continuous usage and perhaps lack of anonymity, in order to remain effective. In the absence of explicit social structures and reputational concerns that prevent deviations from societal norms, individuals from highly cooperative cultures (e.g., Bali) are no more prosocial than participants from relatively individualistic Western cultures (e.g., England).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Consequently, attempts to artificially produce prosocial norm spillovers in a purely lab‐based setting (e.g., Peysakhovich & Rand, ) cannot tell us much about the extent to which cultural and societal norms are internalized by individuals in the real world (Galizzi & Navarro‐Martínez, ). Finally, our results suggest that many social and cultural incentives that sustain volunteering (Chen et al, ), such as favorable public recognition and associated feelings of pride, are not fully internalized, and are therefore “fragile” in the sense that they require continuous usage and perhaps lack of anonymity, in order to remain effective. In the absence of explicit social structures and reputational concerns that prevent deviations from societal norms, individuals from highly cooperative cultures (e.g., Bali) are no more prosocial than participants from relatively individualistic Western cultures (e.g., England).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Beyond economics and game theory, the VDG has also been used to explain the evolution of volunteering in a society (Chen, Gross, & Dieckmann, ; He, Wang, & Li, ; Myatt & Wallace, ), the vigilance behavior of prey animals (Archetti, ), and the functional dynamics of viruses, bacteria, amoeba, and yeast (Archetti, ). The VDG also relates to the social psychological literature on the diffusion of responsibility (also known as the “bystander effect”; Darley & Latané, ; Latané & Darley, , ; Latané & Rodin, ; for a more recent review and meta‐analysis see Fischer et al, ), whereby people are less likely to help a person in need of assistance (e.g., someone injured and calling for help) if others around them did not react to the incident.…”
Section: The Volunteer's Dilemma Game (Vdg)mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While most theoretical and empirical studies focused on incentive systems where sanctions or rewards are administered by peers [11,[13][14][15][16][17][18][19][20][21][22][23][24], it is only recently that scholars have started to investigate mechanisms that can be viewed as primitive institutions, namely 'pool' mechanisms [25][26][27][28][29][30][31]. The idea is that individuals can decide to pool their effort and provision an incentive fund before contributing to the PGG.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Recently, ample research efforts have been devoted to the study of the emergence of institutions and their effectiveness in promoting prosocial behavior (Yamagishi, 1986; Ostrom, 1990; Gurerk et al, 2006; Henrich, 2006; Cuesta et al, 2008; Sigmund et al, 2010; Baldassarri and Grossman, 2011; Sasaki and Unemi, 2011; Szolnoki et al, 2011a,b; Cressman et al, 2012; Isakov and Rand, 2012; Sasaki et al, 2012; Bechtel and Scheve, 2013; Cressman et al, 2013; Vasconcelos et al, 2013; Vukov et al, 2013). It has been shown, for example, that institutional rewarding promotes the evolution of cooperation in the liner public goods game (Cuesta et al, 2008), the nonlinear public goods games (Chen et al, 2013), and in structured populations in general (Jiménez et al, 2008, 2009; Szolnoki et al, 2011a,b). However, institutional punishment is less costly and thus more effective to warrant a given level of public cooperation, especially if participation in the public goods game is optional (Sasaki et al, 2012; Sasaki, 2013).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Surprisingly, few studies have thus far considered the problem of the optimal allocation of incentives for maximizing public cooperation. Traditionally, all groups and all individuals are considered equal, and depending on their strategies thus deserved of the same reward or punishment (Jiménez et al, 2008; Sasaki et al, 2012; Chen et al, 2013). This simple assumption, however, does not agree with the fact that in social networks individuals have different roles, which depend significantly on the degree of the node that they occupy.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%