1999
DOI: 10.3386/w7240
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Social Approval, Values, and AFDC: A Re-Examination of the Illegitimacy Debate

Abstract: Empirical attempts to link teenage out-of-wedlock births to the incentive structure of Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) have met with mixed results. This has suggested to many researchers that, while the AFDC program contains incentives for poor women to have children out-ofwedlock, these incentives cannot be the primary culprit responsible for current levels of out-of-wedlock births. This paper presents a model that is consistent with the stylized facts and the empirical evidence but establishes… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

2
8
0

Year Published

2002
2002
2010
2010

Publication Types

Select...
4
1
1

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 11 publications
(10 citation statements)
references
References 7 publications
2
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Nechyba (1999) constructs a theoretical model in which social interactions between low income families causes lags in the response to a change in benefits, consistent with the hypothesis that rising welfare benefits in the late 1960s and early 1970s could have had lagged effects over the next two decades (a hypothesis also suggested by Murray (1984)). Moffitt (2000) takes a more direct approach and conducts a time series analysis of the relative importance of trends in female wages, male wages, and welfare benefits, and finds that a decline in the wages of less educated males was the main contributor to the rise in female headship, and that the decline in welfare benefits slowed that rise, thus providing one possible reconciliation between the cross-sectional and time-series evidence.…”
supporting
confidence: 67%
“…Nechyba (1999) constructs a theoretical model in which social interactions between low income families causes lags in the response to a change in benefits, consistent with the hypothesis that rising welfare benefits in the late 1960s and early 1970s could have had lagged effects over the next two decades (a hypothesis also suggested by Murray (1984)). Moffitt (2000) takes a more direct approach and conducts a time series analysis of the relative importance of trends in female wages, male wages, and welfare benefits, and finds that a decline in the wages of less educated males was the main contributor to the rise in female headship, and that the decline in welfare benefits slowed that rise, thus providing one possible reconciliation between the cross-sectional and time-series evidence.…”
supporting
confidence: 67%
“…Benefit levels of states tend to be highly correlated with marginal benefit levels in those same states, making it difficult for researchers to determine which component is truly driving any fertility effect (Camasso, 2004). Cross-state comparisons are also subject to unobserved differences, which may cause benefit levels and fertility to covary across states, irrespective of any welfare policy changes (Hoynes, 1997;Nechyba, 2001).…”
Section: The Research On Welfare Benefits and Fertilitymentioning
confidence: 96%
“…We initially treat fertility decisions within an economic framework where the family is assumed to maximize utility (which includes the number of children as an argument) subject to constraints on its resources of money and time (Becker, 1991(Becker, , 1996Cigno, 1991). Nechyba (2001) maintains that the frequency of out-of-wedlock births in a community determine the level of social approval enjoyed by a woman if she herself becomes a single mother. Following Becker (1996) and Coleman (1990), it would be expected that women with high stocks of social capital invested in community networks that condone a reliance on public assistance would ignore the advice (threat) of a Family Cap and its message of personal responsibility for childbearing decisions.…”
Section: Conceptual Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 97%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…From the perspective of economic theorizing, the study of social interactions is important as it integrates substantive sociological ideas with formal economic reasoning. Early applications of social interactions to substantive theoretical problems include analyses of patterns of residential segregation (Schelling, 1971) and racial inequality (Loury, 1977); recent contributions include volatility in financial markets (Brock, 1993), cross-city variation in crime (Glaeser et al, 1996), and labor market versus welfare dependence (Lindbeck et al, 1999;Nechyba, 2001). Social interactions models may also be understood as exploring the consequences for individuals of their location in social space (cf.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 98%