“…While many authors have explored the reasons for declining marriage rates, and accompanying increases in non-marital fertility(Akerlof et al, 1996;Mechoulan, 2011;Duncan and Hoffman, 1990;Rosenzweig, 1999;Nechyba, 2001;Neal, 2004), ours is the first to explore the role of assets in substituting for other legal protections. We also relate to literature looking at the strengthening of non-marital contracting, including child support enforcement in the US(Aizer and McLanahan, 2005; Tannenbaum, 2015;Rossin-Slater, 2017;Brown et al, 2015), common law marriage(Grossbard andVernon, 2015, 2014), and protections for cohabitants in other countries(Chiappori et al, 2017b;Chigavazira et al, 2019).4 In this way, our model is unique from literature that has framed women's labor supply as reflecting bargaining power to spend time on leisure (e.g.,Chiappori et al, 2002;Voena, 2015; and Chiappori and Oreffice, 2008) by emphasizing the productive value of time away from work for creating household public goods.5 This is an application of the general result that limited commitment reduces risk-sharing between agents, seeKocherlakota (1996).6 The positive role of a "storage" technology was discussed in the more general problem of limited commitment by ÁrpádÁbrahám and Laczó (2018).7 If offered the choice, the couple will always prefer to save in this "high commitment device," since it moves them closer to the full-commitment optimum. In fact even if the decision were in the hands of the husband, he would choose to save in the vehicle with stronger commitment as long as he values child quality sufficiently highly relative to second-period consumption.…”