2009
DOI: 10.1007/s10797-009-9109-0
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The effect of benefits level on take-up rates: evidence from a natural experiment

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
16
0

Year Published

2010
2010
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

3
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 14 publications
(16 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
0
16
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Most economic analyses of take‐up behaviour have considered claiming as a utility maximizing choice (see Moffitt 1983; Blundell et al . 1988; Duclos 1995; Anderson and Meyer 1997; Dahan and Nisan 2007; Pudney et al .…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Most economic analyses of take‐up behaviour have considered claiming as a utility maximizing choice (see Moffitt 1983; Blundell et al . 1988; Duclos 1995; Anderson and Meyer 1997; Dahan and Nisan 2007; Pudney et al .…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Most economic analyses of take-up behaviour have considered claiming as a utility maximizing choice (see Moffitt 1983;Blundell et al 1988;Duclos 1995;Anderson and Meyer 1997;Dahan and Nisan 2007;Pudney et al 2006a;Hernandez et al 2007). The individual compares expected benefits from claiming with the inherent costs of applying, and chooses to claim only if the expected benefit adequately compensates the costs.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In other words, a 10% increase in financial entitlement results in an estimated take‐up increase of 6 to 12%. These results are consistent with the well established empirical finding of a positive correlation between entitlement amounts and take‐up behavior, and with the causal role of monetary incentives as take‐up triggers established in a few other studies (Anderson and Meyer, , reporting an entitlement elasticity ranging from 0.33 to 0.6; Zantomio et al ., , whose estimates reflect an entitlement elasticity of about 0.5; Dahan and Nisan, , who however do not report any figure on the estimated entitlement elasticity of take‐up).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…Most have obtained the result exploiting the cross-sectional variation of entitlement levels across the eligible population (Warlick, 1982;Ashenfelter, 1983;Moffitt, 1983;Halpern and Hausman, 1986;McGarry, 1996). A few have gone further towards causality by exploiting exogenous changes in program parameters to identify a positive entitlement elasticity of take-up behavior (Anderson and Meyer, 1997;Dahan and Nisan, 2010;Zantomio, Pudney and Hancock, 2010). On the other hand, very little is known about individuals' responsiveness to policies aimed at reducing claiming barriers.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A standard cost-benefits model suggests that eligible households would apply if the expected benefits are higher than the cost (See [3] and more recently [4]). The straightforward implication is that for a given level of benefits a negative relation exists between the costs and take-up rates of social benefits.…”
Section: Open Accessmentioning
confidence: 99%