1999
DOI: 10.2307/3857639
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Great Illusion: Ignorance, Informational Cascades, and the Persistence of Unpopular Norms

Abstract: Norms of discrimination against women and blacks, norms of revenge still alive in some Mediterranean countries, and norms that everybody dislikes and tries to circumvent, such as the invisible norms of reciprocity that hold among the Iks studied by Turnbull, are all examples of unpopular and inefficient norms that often persist in spite of their being disliked as well as being obviously inefficient from a social or economic viewpoint. The world of business is not immune to this problem. In all those countries … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
10
0

Year Published

2009
2009
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 47 publications
(10 citation statements)
references
References 4 publications
0
10
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Knowing that the majority will commit to the alternative norm in the present may lead to a change of the current norm if everyone is aware that the outcome of that change will be experienced immediately rather than after a time lag. For example, in the case of corruption norms, Bicchieri and Fukui [5] argue that more information dissemination on the true beliefs of businesspeople (i.e., condemning corruption) will lead to the change of such an unpopular norm. We add to this argument that such change may occur because, in that example, the consequences for businesspeople to operate in a ‘clean’ and fair business environment are close in time to their decision to commit to the alternative norm.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Knowing that the majority will commit to the alternative norm in the present may lead to a change of the current norm if everyone is aware that the outcome of that change will be experienced immediately rather than after a time lag. For example, in the case of corruption norms, Bicchieri and Fukui [5] argue that more information dissemination on the true beliefs of businesspeople (i.e., condemning corruption) will lead to the change of such an unpopular norm. We add to this argument that such change may occur because, in that example, the consequences for businesspeople to operate in a ‘clean’ and fair business environment are close in time to their decision to commit to the alternative norm.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There is, however, substantial evidence of norms that harm those who comply. Examples are norms on footbinding in China [4], female circumcision in Africa [4], bribery and corruption in various cultures [5], the mass suicide of Jim Jones’ sect when it was threatened in Guyana [6], and the easy access to and possession of guns in the United States. Although a majority of individuals may disapprove of such norms when asked individually, the pertaining group collectively conforms to them.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…It is possible that unpopular norms are established, which are not aligned with the preferences of the majority [77], [90][91].…”
Section: Methodsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In the example above it was mentioned that agent 2 could deduce the left signal of agent 1 and, given that 2 received a right signal, he should invoke a tie‐breaking rule in order to decide what choice to make. Examples of such tie‐breaking rules may be to randomize the available option (Bicchieri and Fukui ; Bikchandani et al. 1992), choose an externally given option (Banerjee ; Bikchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch 1992), act in accordance with a private signal/preference (Anderson and Holt ; Banerjee ; Bicchieri and Fukui ), or something else.…”
Section: The Structure Of Information Problems and Processesmentioning
confidence: 99%