1998
DOI: 10.1111/1475-6765.00404
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The impact of constitutional structures and collective and competitive veto points on income inequality in industrialized democracies

Abstract: This paper presents the first systematic, empirical examination of the impact of constitutional structures on income inequality among eighteen OECD countries. Our pooled time series/cross-sectional panel analysis (n = 18, t = 2) reveals that consensual political institutions are systematically related to lower income inequalities while the reverse is true for majoritarian political institutions. We also make a crucial distinction between 'collective' and 'competitive' veto points. Our multiple regression resul… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

2
99
0
1

Year Published

2002
2002
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 193 publications
(102 citation statements)
references
References 34 publications
2
99
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…If a government intends to govern for the long-term (Jacobs, 2011), however, it makes sense to include all the relevant actors in a reform coalition, to build a consensus and generate trust that costs are shared equally by all actors, and to beware of aggressive cost-externalization. This makes it feasible to invest in the long-term, making compromises and sacrifices in order to facilitate a sound fiscal position and a sustainable welfare state in the future, and to steer clear of short-sighted populist initiatives for immediate but short-lived political gain (see also the argument about cooperative veto-points by Birchfeld & Crepaz, 1998;Crepaz, 1996;Crepaz, 1998). A major advantage of this approach is the reduction of the electoral costs of austerity and social security cutbacks.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…If a government intends to govern for the long-term (Jacobs, 2011), however, it makes sense to include all the relevant actors in a reform coalition, to build a consensus and generate trust that costs are shared equally by all actors, and to beware of aggressive cost-externalization. This makes it feasible to invest in the long-term, making compromises and sacrifices in order to facilitate a sound fiscal position and a sustainable welfare state in the future, and to steer clear of short-sighted populist initiatives for immediate but short-lived political gain (see also the argument about cooperative veto-points by Birchfeld & Crepaz, 1998;Crepaz, 1996;Crepaz, 1998). A major advantage of this approach is the reduction of the electoral costs of austerity and social security cutbacks.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…4, No. 5; years, scholars have demonstrated powerful synergies between political institutions such as the electoral system and economic and social institutions such as the system of interest group representation (e.g., Birchfield & Crepaz, 1998;Crepaz & Moser, 2004;Iversen, 2005;Lijphart, 1999) (Note 14). If the economies of advanced industrialized democracies cluster in groups that are institutionally congruent (Hall & Soskice, 2001), then model covariates may explain dependent variables through more than one path.…”
Section: Review Of European Studiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As scholars have pointed out, both factors are inversely related to the capacity of a political system to implement new fiscal policies (Birchfield and Crepaz, 1998;Crepaz, 1998Crepaz, , 2002Crepaz and Moser, 2004). In the era of globalization, however, it is possible that dispersion of power through constitutional structures can work "in favour of more generous welfare states, by slowing down retrenchment" (Huber & Stephens, 2001, p. 32).…”
Section: Budget Deficitmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In the case of (one-party) minority governments, opposition parties are disregarded completely, based on the argument that in general they do not have effective veto power. Lijphart's approach (1999b) -linked to veto player theory by Birchfield and Crepaz (1998;see also Crepaz 2004) -is more ambiguous. In search for a theoretical rationale behind the two empirically identified dimensions of democracy, Lijphart draws on Goodin (1996) and argues that policymaking interactions along the executive-party dimension are characterized by "collective agency and shared responsibility", while those along the federal-unitary dimension are not.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%