2007
DOI: 10.1145/1236457.1236461
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

When are elections with few candidates hard to manipulate?

Abstract: In multiagent settings where the agents have different preferences, preference aggregation is a central issue. Voting is a general method for preference aggregation, but seminal results have shown that all general voting protocols are manipulable. One could try to avoid manipulation by using protocols where determining a beneficial manipulation is hard. Especially among computational agents, it is reasonable to measure this hardness by computational complexity. Some earlier work has been done in this area, but… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
5

Citation Types

1
273
0
1

Year Published

2009
2009
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
5
2

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 234 publications
(275 citation statements)
references
References 18 publications
1
273
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…We test the running times of our algorithms empirically. Algorithmic problems that model the manipulation of elections include, among others, strategic voting problems [1,6] (where we are given an election with honest voters Supported by DFG project PAWS (NI 369/10). Supported by a DFG Mercator fellowship within project PAWS (NI 369/10) while staying at TU Berlin, and by AGH University grant 11.11.230.124 afterward.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…We test the running times of our algorithms empirically. Algorithmic problems that model the manipulation of elections include, among others, strategic voting problems [1,6] (where we are given an election with honest voters Supported by DFG project PAWS (NI 369/10). Supported by a DFG Mercator fellowship within project PAWS (NI 369/10) while staying at TU Berlin, and by AGH University grant 11.11.230.124 afterward.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We focus on the case where we have a few candidates but (possibly) many voters. As pointed out by Conitzer et al [6], this is a very natural setting and it models many real-life scenarios such as political elections or elections among company stockholders.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Formally, in the coalitional manipulation problem, introduced by Conitzer, Sandholm, and Lang [5], the voters are divided into two groups, the manipulators and the nonmanipulators. The votes of the nonmanipulators are assumed to be known, and the problem is to determine whether the manipulators can use their votes to achieve a given goal.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As in most of the literature on voting, we assume that the agents do not have the ability to make or receive payments, so that we are in the nontransferable utility (NTU) case of cooperative game theory. (Recently, Bachrach, Elkind, and Faliszewski [2] studied a similar problem in the transferable utility setting, and obtained results linking coalitional manipulation [5] and bribery [6] problems with their cooperative gametheoretic model.) Moreover, in this setting, what one (sub)coalition of manipulators can achieve depends on the actions (votes) of the manipulators outside the coalition.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%