2011
DOI: 10.1016/j.econlet.2011.07.016
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Do FOMC members herd?

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
19
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

1
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 28 publications
(22 citation statements)
references
References 11 publications
3
19
0
Order By: Relevance
“…11 Table 4 presents the results for differences in the voting status. Existing literature suggests significant differences of individual macroeconomic forecasts among voting and nonvoting Bank presidents, with nonvoters submitting extreme inflation forecasts for strategic reasons (see, e.g., Rülke & Tillmann, 2011;Tillmann, 2011). These differences in the voting status among Bank presidents may also explain their different intensities of regional bias when forming macroeconomic forecasts.…”
Section: Eichler and Lähner 125mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…11 Table 4 presents the results for differences in the voting status. Existing literature suggests significant differences of individual macroeconomic forecasts among voting and nonvoting Bank presidents, with nonvoters submitting extreme inflation forecasts for strategic reasons (see, e.g., Rülke & Tillmann, 2011;Tillmann, 2011). These differences in the voting status among Bank presidents may also explain their different intensities of regional bias when forming macroeconomic forecasts.…”
Section: Eichler and Lähner 125mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Additionally, he concludes that nonvoting Bank presidents do not differ from their voting counterparts, as opposed to Tillmann (2011), who find that nonvoting FOMC members tend to submit extreme inflation forecasts to influence policy. What is more, particular nonvoting FOMC members show a tendency for antiherding when submitting inflation forecasts; that is, they place them more away from consensus (Rülke & Tillmann, 2011). McCracken (2010 argues that FOMC members have an incentive to forecast strategically; that is, they submit forecasts in line with their preferences of being either an inflation hawk (higher desired interest rates)-possibly leading to higher individual inflation forecasts-or an inflation "dove" (lower desired interest rates)-possibly leading to lower individual inflation forecasts regardless of the stance of the economy.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Our usage of the term herding, thus, should not be confused with the terminology used by other researchers who utilize the term herding to describe, for example, destabilizing trend-extrapolative forecasts in a time series context. 7 Recent applications of their empirical test focus on oil-price forecasts (Pierdzioch et al, 2010), car sale forecasts (Pierdzioch et al, 2011) and central bank forecasts (Rülke and Tillmann, 2011 forecasts further away from the consensus than they would have performed otherwise. Our finding of significant cross-sectional heterogeneity of forecasts in Section 3 could suggest that anti-herding is particularly prevalent among analysts participating in the Consensus Economics forecast poll.…”
Section: A Test For Herding and Anti-herdingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“… Recent applications of their empirical test focus on oil‐price forecasts (Pierdzioch et al , ), car sale forecasts (Pierdzioch et al , ) and central bank forecasts (Rülke and Tillmann, ).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%