2013
DOI: 10.1111/faf.12015
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Does ‘race to fish’ behaviour emerge in an individual transferable quota fishery when the total allowable catch becomes non‐binding?

Abstract: Successful individual transferable quota (ITQ) management requires a binding (constraining) total allowable catch (TAC). A non‐binding TAC may result in a shift back towards open access conditions, where fishers increasingly compete (‘race’) to catch their share of the total harvest. This process was examined by comparing fishing fleet behaviour and profitability in the Tasmanian southern rock lobster (Jasus edwardsii) fishery (TSRLF), Australia. Between 2008 and 2010, the TSRLF had a non‐binding TAC and effec… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
11
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 26 publications
(11 citation statements)
references
References 48 publications
0
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Evidence for the social costs of power disconnects associated with ITQs is extensive, but bioeconomic benefits have also been diluted as powerful quota-holders lobby to raise catch limits above scientifically recommended levels to maintain the "value" of their quota (18,(91)(92)(93). Ecologically, locked-in ITQs are ill-suited to handling the nonlinearities and interconnections occurring in dynamic marine systems.…”
Section: Power Disconnectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Evidence for the social costs of power disconnects associated with ITQs is extensive, but bioeconomic benefits have also been diluted as powerful quota-holders lobby to raise catch limits above scientifically recommended levels to maintain the "value" of their quota (18,(91)(92)(93). Ecologically, locked-in ITQs are ill-suited to handling the nonlinearities and interconnections occurring in dynamic marine systems.…”
Section: Power Disconnectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This observation reinforces the need to approach the problem of fisheries capacity management as an issue at the sectorial or multi-fishery, rather than single fishery, level (Holland 1999) and makes the question of how best to manage existing capacity in such fisheries to meet economic, social, and environmental goals as they transition to regulated fisheries, of central importance. Furthermore, the importance of designing effective capacity management policies goes beyond the case of the fishery where fishing regulations are either absent or ineffective, as incentives to compete in harvesting and investment among fishers is evident in fisheries under a range of regulatory regimes, including individual transferable quotas (Costello and Deacon 2007;Emery et al 2014).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While such behavior can persist in regulated fisheries (Homans and Wilen 1997) and under a range of property institutions, including rights-based regimes (Costello and Deacon 2007;Asche et al 2008;Emery et al 2014), the twin problems of race to fish and race to invest behavior are most pervasive in fisheries where access is unrestricted and fishing regulations are ineffective. In the fishery literature, overcapacity and excess capacity are defined as separate concepts and treated as different issues.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The effectiveness of TAC systems generally depends on whether: (i) the actual catch in the fishery does not exceed the TAC; and (ii) the TAC is binding or close to binding (Grafton et al ; Kompas and Gooday ). When the TAC is non‐binding, the fishery’s yield or effort is, in effect, not constrained by the TAC (Emery et al ; Rust et al ). The TAC for the Japanese sardine has not been binding in any year since the management system was introduced to the fishery (FA ).…”
Section: Empirical Application: the Japanese Sardine Pacific Stock Fimentioning
confidence: 99%