2009
DOI: 10.1088/1367-2630/11/8/083031
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Evolutionary game dynamics in a growing structured population

Help me understand this report
View preprint versions

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

3
97
0

Year Published

2009
2009
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
3

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 139 publications
(100 citation statements)
references
References 50 publications
3
97
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The emergence of cooperation and the phase transitions leading to other favorable evolutionary outcomes depend sensitively on the structure of the interaction network and the type of interactions, as well as on the number and type of competing strategies [32][33][34][35][36][37][38][39][40][41][42][43][44][45]. Studies making use of statistical physics and network science have led to significant advances in our understanding of the evolution of cooperation, for example by expanding our understanding of the role of heterogeneity of interaction networks [35,46], the dynamical organization of cooperation [38] and population growth [47], the emergence of hierarchy among competing individuals [39], as well as the intriguing role of strategic complexity [41,43], to name just some examples. Most recently, evidence in support of the fact that static networks promote cooperation in human experiments have also been presented [48], in addition to the fact that this has been shown already before for networks with rewiring [49].…”
Section: Collective Behavior and Evolutionary Gamesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The emergence of cooperation and the phase transitions leading to other favorable evolutionary outcomes depend sensitively on the structure of the interaction network and the type of interactions, as well as on the number and type of competing strategies [32][33][34][35][36][37][38][39][40][41][42][43][44][45]. Studies making use of statistical physics and network science have led to significant advances in our understanding of the evolution of cooperation, for example by expanding our understanding of the role of heterogeneity of interaction networks [35,46], the dynamical organization of cooperation [38] and population growth [47], the emergence of hierarchy among competing individuals [39], as well as the intriguing role of strategic complexity [41,43], to name just some examples. Most recently, evidence in support of the fact that static networks promote cooperation in human experiments have also been presented [48], in addition to the fact that this has been shown already before for networks with rewiring [49].…”
Section: Collective Behavior and Evolutionary Gamesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Since it not only reflects the evolving of strategies over time, but also characterizes the adaptive development of the network topologies or the update rules (for a further review see [33]). For instance, in [34][35][36] the rewiring of existing links was recognized as very beneficial to the evolution of cooperation, the growth of a network had a positive p-1 impact on the evolution of cooperation in [41][42][43], and cooperation could also be promoted when the coevolution of strategies and update rules were considered [44,45]. Take some multinational corporations as examples, these corporations often extend their business to different countries or regions to pursue their maximal profit.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The choice of τ D /τ T < 1 leads to a situation in which cooperation and defection cannot coexist as the system dynamics evolves either to an all-C or to all-D configuration. Other rules for nodes attachment and evolutionary dynamics might change both the topological and dynamical features of the system [27]. We stress that our main goal is to show that there are networks for which defector hubs can be asymptotically stable, for which it is enough to find one network generation recipe.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%