2014
DOI: 10.2753/pin1099-9922160403
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Concept of Political Corruption

Abstract: Doron navot abstractThis article revises the concept of political corruption by bringing a fresh perspective to prebehavioral scholarship. It acknowledges prior scholarship but also recognizes its limitations. By refuting the assertion that early twentieth-century conceptions are irrelevant, understanding of political corruption and public integrity can be enhanced.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
4
4
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 16 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 19 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The idea that corruption persists because it fulfills political, social, and economic functions is one with a long historical pedigree, certainly longer than much contemporary corruption/anticorruption research acknowledges. Navot (, p. 359), for example, writes of a “lost epoch” of research on political corruption in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, which he argues attempted “to move away from understanding political corruption in purely moralistic terms.” Arguably, the notion peaked in popularity a half a century ago, as it was a theme prominent in many works within the development of modernization theory; from the 1950s until the early 1970s, this dominant academic discourse on corruption maintained a “functionalist approach,” which essentially argued that corruption functions in positive ways and as a result facilitates both political and economic development (Osrecki, ).…”
Section: The Problem With Viewing Corruption As Only a “Problem”mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The idea that corruption persists because it fulfills political, social, and economic functions is one with a long historical pedigree, certainly longer than much contemporary corruption/anticorruption research acknowledges. Navot (, p. 359), for example, writes of a “lost epoch” of research on political corruption in the late 19th and early 20th centuries, which he argues attempted “to move away from understanding political corruption in purely moralistic terms.” Arguably, the notion peaked in popularity a half a century ago, as it was a theme prominent in many works within the development of modernization theory; from the 1950s until the early 1970s, this dominant academic discourse on corruption maintained a “functionalist approach,” which essentially argued that corruption functions in positive ways and as a result facilitates both political and economic development (Osrecki, ).…”
Section: The Problem With Viewing Corruption As Only a “Problem”mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Finding its roots in a long historical pedigree, the functionality perspective on corruption suggests that, for many, corruption serves specific social, economic and/or political functions, and because of this, proclivity to engage in corruption may be relatively unchanged by principal–agent theory‐inspired anticorruption efforts (Huntington, 1968; Khan, 2004, 2006; Leff, 1964; Marquette & Peiffer, 2018, 2019; Navot, 2014; Osrecki, 2017). In other words, corruption may persist even if principals are committed to implementing anticorruption reforms, because corruption works to solve the problems that principals and/or agents face.…”
Section: The Hmu As a “Conflicted Success” Storymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In order to address these issues, typologies have been often used to better distinguish corrupt behaviors not only on the basis of specific mechanisms, attributes, procedures and sectors, but also in relation to precise personal attitudes and motivations. The most common classifications of corruption are those distinguishing between grand and petty corruption (Rose-Ackerman, 1978), administrative and political corruption (Gould, 1991;Huberts, 1998;Navot, 2014, Holmes, 2015OECD, 2015;World Bank, 2003), illegal and legal corruption (Kaufmann & Vicente, 2011;Maciel & De Sousa, 2018); the type of gain (tangible or intangible) involved in the transaction (UNODC, 2006;OECD, 2007;OECD, 2008;Villeneuve et al, 2019) and the principal's or agent's motivation for participating in the transaction (collusive vs. extortionary corruption) (Bauhr & Grimes, 2017;Jancsics, 2019;Ryvkin et al, 2017).…”
Section: Challenges In Defining and Measuring Corruptionmentioning
confidence: 99%