2001
DOI: 10.2307/2669362
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Politics of Blame: Bargaining before an Audience

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

12
172
0

Year Published

2004
2004
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 279 publications
(184 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
12
172
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In other words, we do not consider constellations of the "blame game" type (Groseclose and McCarty 2001), in which a government may value the mobilizing effect of an oppositional veto for its own electoral constituency. Given the very small number of government bills that actually fail because of a veto in the second chamber, we think it safe to assume that a government actually wants to get its bills through parliament most of the time.…”
Section: Legislative Self-restraint and Compromise Under Divided Govementioning
confidence: 99%
“…In other words, we do not consider constellations of the "blame game" type (Groseclose and McCarty 2001), in which a government may value the mobilizing effect of an oppositional veto for its own electoral constituency. Given the very small number of government bills that actually fail because of a veto in the second chamber, we think it safe to assume that a government actually wants to get its bills through parliament most of the time.…”
Section: Legislative Self-restraint and Compromise Under Divided Govementioning
confidence: 99%
“…20 The unanimity requirement implies that the set of equilibrium outcomes is the (nonempty) subset of P (C 2 , g 1 ) containing all the levels of public spending which are Pareto optimal for the coalition members. With respect to the reform issue, the first-period decision will be reversed (i.e.…”
Section: Political Equilibriummentioning
confidence: 99%
“…where m is the ego rent it gets when C 2 = C. Thus party i agrees to join coalition C if and only if 20 Note that P (C 2 , g 1 ) is non-empty since either…”
Section: Government Formation Let V I Be the Number Of Votes Party Imentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The agenda setter can include as few, or as many, private items in the bill as she wishes whereas our previous results indicated that there was generally a limited on the number of private goods the agenda setter would want to include. If the legislators' motives include embarrassing the executive by 'forcing' him to veto popular projects, as Burkhead (1956) and Groseclose and McCarty (2000) suggest, then the individual item override has potentially negative consequences for the executive. That is, adding an private good to a bill has no consequences for the legislators but forces the executive to make unpopular choices.…”
Section: Proposition 4 Under the Line-item With Individual Item Overrmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Models of veto bargaining don't address one of the concerns voiced by opponents of the item veto either-legislators' incentive to pass bills unacceptable to the president while claiming credit for their attempts to do so in their constituency. The presence of credit claiming incentives 8 explains the executive's use of the item (and the package) veto without assuming that legislators (e.g., Cameron 2000;Matthews 1989;McCarty 1997) or voters (e.g., Groseclose and McCarty 2000) are simply badly informed about the executive's preferences. Vetoes do occur in Magar's (2001) complete information model where the actors derive utility from taking a stand by proposing bills that will be vetoed or using vetoes that the legislature will override.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%