2007
DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.2007.00327.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A Convex Stochastic Optimization Problem Arising From Portfolio Selection

Abstract: A continuous-time financial portfolio selection model with expected utility maximization typically boils down to solving a (static) convex stochastic optimization problem in terms of the terminal wealth, with a budget constraint. In literature the latter is solved by assuming a priori that the problem is well-posed (i.e., the supremum value is finite) and a Lagrange multiplier exists (and as a consequence the optimal solution is attainable). In this paper it is first shown that, via various counter-examples, n… Show more

Help me understand this report
View preprint versions

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
53
0

Year Published

2008
2008
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
3
3
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 86 publications
(53 citation statements)
references
References 7 publications
0
53
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Compared with , the positive part problem (8) here is unaffected by the loss constraint L; and a more general version of it has been solved already in Jin and Zhou (2008), Appendix C. The only difference here lies in the negative part problem (9) where there is an additional upper bound constraint on X. This, certainly, is due to the loss control in the original model.…”
Section: Solution Scheme: Divide and Conquermentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Compared with , the positive part problem (8) here is unaffected by the loss constraint L; and a more general version of it has been solved already in Jin and Zhou (2008), Appendix C. The only difference here lies in the negative part problem (9) where there is an additional upper bound constraint on X. This, certainly, is due to the loss control in the original model.…”
Section: Solution Scheme: Divide and Conquermentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The positive part problem (8) in this example (where A = {ρ ≤ c}) has been solved explicitly by with the following results:…”
Section: An Example With Two-piece Power Utilitymentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The unconstrained problem (5.15), which is referred as the static reformulation of Merton's problem in complete markets, has been heavily investigated in the literature with slight differences; see, e.g., Pliska (1986), Cox and Huang (1989), Karatzas et al (1987) and Jin et al (2008). For extensions to incomplete markets, see He and Pearson (1991), Karatzas et al (1991), among others.…”
Section: Expected Utility Maximizationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Moreover, the properties of the minimal probability in [1, Remark 4], especially properties 1. and 3., make it desirable to use Q ν in Problem (CPT-I). 5 Furthermore, dropping the distinction between losses and gains and probability distortions as well, we recover Problem (EU-I). On the other hand, in the extreme case of no additional information ν = Q Y we have V ν ± (X) = V ± (X) thanks to minimal probability's property 3 in [1, Remark 4], so we turn back to Problem (CPT-N).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%