2009
DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01510.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Momentum, Reversal, and Uninformed Traders in Laboratory Markets

Abstract: We report the results of three experiments based on the model of Hong and Stein (1999) . Consistent with the model, the results show that when informed traders do not observe prices, uninformed traders generate long-term price reversals by engaging in momentum trade. However, when informed traders also observe prices, uninformed traders generate reversals by engaging in contrarian trading. The results suggest that a dominated information set is sufficient to account for the contrarian behavior observed among i… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
17
0

Year Published

2010
2010
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 51 publications
(19 citation statements)
references
References 27 publications
2
17
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Some models rely on segmented investors, such as sophisticated α-investors and purely trend-following β-investors introduced by Day and Huang (1990), such as Chiarella, Dieci, and Gardini (2002), or segmented markets, such as in Wester-hoff (2004). The results of these simulation studies are largely consistent with highly stylized facts of financial markets and observations in experimental asset markets, where, usually, students form expectations about future asset prices and operate in a dynamic market setting (see, e.g., Sonnemans, Hommes, Tuinstra, and Van De Velden, 2004;Haruvy, Lahav, and Noussair, 2007;Bloomfield, Tayler, and Zhou, 2009;Hommes, 2011). Results are also consistent with models from behavioral finance, such as Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), where investors believe in two states of the world, i.e.…”
Section: Literature and Hypothesessupporting
confidence: 74%
“…Some models rely on segmented investors, such as sophisticated α-investors and purely trend-following β-investors introduced by Day and Huang (1990), such as Chiarella, Dieci, and Gardini (2002), or segmented markets, such as in Wester-hoff (2004). The results of these simulation studies are largely consistent with highly stylized facts of financial markets and observations in experimental asset markets, where, usually, students form expectations about future asset prices and operate in a dynamic market setting (see, e.g., Sonnemans, Hommes, Tuinstra, and Van De Velden, 2004;Haruvy, Lahav, and Noussair, 2007;Bloomfield, Tayler, and Zhou, 2009;Hommes, 2011). Results are also consistent with models from behavioral finance, such as Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), where investors believe in two states of the world, i.e.…”
Section: Literature and Hypothesessupporting
confidence: 74%
“…[10][11][12]. Various types of agents are also modeled, such as fundamentalists, chartists and noisy traders, momentum traders and reverse momentum traders [13][14][15]. While the models become more realistic, they usually end up being too complex for thorough understanding and analytical treatment.…”
Section: Winnermentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Similarly, in financial markets, groups and individuals may have contrary aims. For example, in European and America stock markets, the investors are classified into informed investors and uninformed investors [15]. The informed investors exploit the insider information to make profits, they buy or sell, and wish other investors to choose the opposite action (i.e.…”
Section: Winnermentioning
confidence: 99%
“…7 Alternatively, relatively unsophisticated investors who nevertheless review the financial statements may indeed have a higher level of sophistication (and, therefore, a possible comparative advantage) over others who do not review the financial statements. 8 With the assumption that they can sell the stock at a higher price just prior to the earnings management being revealed to the masses, these investors may attempt to game the market by, for example, aggressively buying the stock, thereby driving prices higher than warranted by fundamental news (Scheinkman and Xiong [2003]; see also Andreassen and Kraus [1990], Bloomfield, Tayler, and Zhou [2009], cf., Badrinath and Wahal [2002]). This potential for multiple differing strategies is consistent with recent evidence from abstract experimental markets, in which more understandable information leads to higher rates of information processing by market participants, but the increased processing, in turn, leads participants to apply various strategies-including not only trading on fundamental value, but also general momentum trading as well as "riding the bubble" (Hobson [2009]).…”
Section: Accounting Disclosure Transparencymentioning
confidence: 99%