2015
DOI: 10.3917/ride.293.0265
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Le logiciel libre et les communs

Abstract: Cet article porte sur les liens qui se sont tissés entre le mouvement du logiciel libre initié par Richard Stallman, les juristes anglo-saxons défendant le domaine public (Lawrence Lessig, James Boyle, Yochai Benkler, etc.) et les chercheurs réunis autour de l’économiste Elinor Ostrom. Il retrace l’histoire de la rencontre entre ces trois groupes d’acteurs au début des années 2000 et en dégage les enjeux : la construction d’une théorie des communs à même d’embrasser ressources physiques et contenus numériques … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
5
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 27 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
1
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…These are embodied in cognitive frames and values that are ontologically distinct from individuals. This framework echoes recent work by Ostrom (2007) challenging the Samuelsonian classification of economic goods: the commons are not defined by their immanent properties (namely rivalry and non-excludability) but by the way resources are regulated (Harribey, 2011;Allaire, 2013;Coriat, 2015;Broca & Coriat, 2015). Notably, on Ostrom's view the commons are characterized by three criteria which match Proudhon's view (Ostrom, 1990).…”
Section: The Second Knowledge Tradeoff : Knowledge As a Cumulative Production Processsupporting
confidence: 68%
“…These are embodied in cognitive frames and values that are ontologically distinct from individuals. This framework echoes recent work by Ostrom (2007) challenging the Samuelsonian classification of economic goods: the commons are not defined by their immanent properties (namely rivalry and non-excludability) but by the way resources are regulated (Harribey, 2011;Allaire, 2013;Coriat, 2015;Broca & Coriat, 2015). Notably, on Ostrom's view the commons are characterized by three criteria which match Proudhon's view (Ostrom, 1990).…”
Section: The Second Knowledge Tradeoff : Knowledge As a Cumulative Production Processsupporting
confidence: 68%
“…Furthermore, the acquisition of a reusable set of skills leads to increased freedom in working wherever they choose (Eghbal, 2016). This is different from the traditional situation of proletarians who are dispossessed from the fruits of their labour, as here the exchange seems to be mutually profitable, even if the goods being swapped – economic profits for the firms, self-realisation and other advantages for volunteers – are different (Broca, 2018). However, the question of developer exploitation must be left open for now, as determining whether an exploitative relationship exists would require empirical evidence of the concrete benefits involved: how much programmers benefit from participating in FOSS versus how much firms benefit, for example.…”
mentioning
confidence: 76%
“…The adoption by IT firms of open source licences subsequently enabled the full integration of FOSS into the IT industry. This constituted an evolution between what Broca (2018) defined as Microsoft’s ‘informational capitalism’ – in which the firm seeks to protect the value of its closed proprietary systems – to Google’s more flexible ‘digital capitalism’ – whereby the firm integrates the commons into its business model and prioritises mobile and cloud business models using big data and artificial intelligence (Rikap and Lundvall, 2020; see also Birkinbine, 2020; Lund and Zukerfeld, 2020). Another integrating factor was the creation of online platforms such as GitHub (in 2005) and Stack Overflow (in 2008).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Studies have therefore focused on defining these new information commons (Broca & Coriat, 2015;Coriat, 2015;Hess & Ostrom, 2007;Zimmermann, 2020), better locating where the scarcity in these digital commons lies in order to help understand the conditions of their existence (Jullien & Roudaut, 2020), and questioning their sustainability (Greco & Floridi, 2004;Potts, 2018). To an extent, some of the analyses suggest that the production of intangible commons may be associated with a new model of socio-economic production, that of commons-based peer production (CBPP) (Arvidsson et al, 2017;Benkler, 2006;Hippel & Krogh, 2003).…”
Section: Maxime Malafosse* Amandine Pascal** and Serge Amabile*** Int...mentioning
confidence: 99%